InvestSMART

A Libs-friendly idea to get abatement revving

Adding an open-ended market element to Greg Hunt's carbon abatement auction could tempt otherwise-frightened firms into the emissions reduction game.
By · 1 Nov 2013
By ·
1 Nov 2013
comments Comments
Upsell Banner

One of the few things we know about Direct Action is that Minister Hunt wants to run an auction process to buy carbon abatement. This auction will select, often years in advance, who will supply the abatement necessary to deliver on the emission reduction targets. 

An auction process supported by a clear process for determining what types of abatement activities qualify, and how abatement will be measured (similar to the Clean Development Mechanism or the NSW Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme), is a major improvement over ill-defined tenders that can involve highly subjective selection criteria that is open to political meddling.  

Another worthy feature that Hunt has outlined is that the government will sign long-term abatement purchasing contracts with winners of the auction. This should provide abatement project developers with a bankable revenue stream that will allow them to access financing essential to make projects a reality. By providing a long-term contract with the government, it obviates the complete lack of credibility that a budget-funded program will maintain its funding beyond the three-year electoral cycle. However, these contracts will need to provide at least 10 years of revenue to make most abatement projects viable.

But a few days ago I wrote (How 'non-delivery' haunts Greg Hunt, October 22) that there was a real risk that a notable proportion of winners of the auction could fail to deliver the quantity of abatement they promise. 

To control for this risk, bidders need to be vetted for their capability to deliver abatement projects before they can qualify to bid in the auctions. Also, contracts should require winning bidders to make-good any shortfall in abatement delivery from their own project by acquiring abatement from others.

But these controls could exclude some innovative firms and technologies. These innovative options may look risky and some may fail to pay off but a handful may deliver substantial reductions in abatement cost. So the government really can’t rely on an auction alone to acquire abatement.

Since I wrote about this a reader pointed out the obvious to me – why not just allow a free market to develop in abatement certificates via private trading exchanges, and the government purchase its abatement through those exchanges rather than an auction?

Such an approach would have some significant advantages over an auction process run by the government. That’s because it would allow people to buy and sell abatement at any time to anyone. No need to worry about qualifying to participate in an auction, no need to lock yourself into a long-term contract with make-good provisions, and no need to fit in with the infrequent timetable of a government auction.

The problem of course is that you place yourself at the mercy of regulatory change, because you lack a long-term contract with the government. The risk of such change is very high, so an auction process, which allocates long-term contracts, is essential.

In the end, the effectiveness of Direct Action would be best served by offering abatement suppliers three options to sell their abatement: 

1) For those who want the security of a long-term contract and have little risk of falling short on abatement delivery they can opt to sell via the auction.

2) In addition to cater for innovative but risky low-cost options the government offers a standing offer of $8 per tonne of certified CO2 abatement open to anyone at any time. This provides some kind of clear direction to the market on a minimum value for abatement.

3) For firms that are willing to take a bit of a risk or who end up able to over-deliver on their auction contracts, they can sell into exchanges. However, government will only buy from these exchanges in the event that acquisition options 1 and 2 fall short of supplying enough abatement to meet the annual abatement target. To cater for budgetary constraints it might specify a maximum price it is willing to pay for domestic abatement credits from the exchanges, after which it will buy international carbon credits (if these are cheaper) to meet its abatement target.

For this to all work effectively the government must include as part of its legislation for Direct Action a minimum annual abatement acquisition target for the next 10 years, and preferably out to 2030. This could then be increased via ministerial decree, but not decreased unless the legislation was changed. This will allow a market to form for abatement credits outside of the auction process.  

In addition, the government must enshrine in legislation the minimum financial budget it will allocate to acquire abatement for each of the next 10 years. For it to be changed it would need to pass the Senate, much like the budget for the Australian Renewable Energy Agency.

The board members that administer the Direct Action acquisition process and fund would be nominated by the government of the day. But to safeguard their independence from political interference they would have to each be approved via a two-thirds majority of the Senate. They would have three-year fixed terms and could not be sacked except for extraordinary circumstances.

Greg Hunt says he has a deep personal commitment to delivering on the government’s emission reduction targets. But you can’t take that to the bank.

If his government is genuinely interested in achieving emission targets, we need to see it enshrined in legislation and institutions that can’t be unwound by a handful of ministers in the Expenditure Review Committee.

Share this article and show your support
Free Membership
Free Membership
Tristan Edis
Tristan Edis
Keep on reading more articles from Tristan Edis. See more articles
Join the conversation
Join the conversation...
There are comments posted so far. Join the conversation, please login or Sign up.